Matt Westover
Political Science 150
Dr. Hawkins
11/1/12
Blog #7
While
electoral systems vary greatly from state to state, there exist a number of
consistencies between them, or rather, links between their electoral systems
and their party systems can be generalized to a couple of key factors. Maurice
Duverger developed a theory, aptly titled “Duverger’s Law”, which states that
single member district plurality (SMDP) systems consistently produce two
effective political parties by either chasing the smaller parties out of the
game altogether, or forcing them to form coalitions, whereas proportional
representation (PR) systems allow for more1.These assertions hold
true where Australia is concerned, and for the remainder of this piece I will
use the Great Down Under as a case study for the validity of Duverger’s law.
To
begin, it is necessary to give a little bit of prerequisite background
information on the form of the electoral system in Australia. The Australian
system typifies an SMDP arrangement, with 148 single-member constituencies
(district magnitude of 1) spread among 6 states and 2 territories2. The
ballot format is that of a preferential list, with rounds of vote counting held
based on preferential rankings until a candidate receives the necessary 50+1
majority. All of the seats in the lower house are appointed in this manner,
that is, by majority rule, and therefore, the system is not a hybrid. The
formula used to translate votes into legislative seats is that of a single
transferable vote system, where one seat is awarded to the one candidate that
emerges victorious in his/her district. There is no election threshold.
Using the Neff
formula proposed by Dr. Kirk Hawkins to table the data from the most recent
Australian Parliamentary elections, one arrives at the conclusion that
Australia has about 4 effective parties3.
Party # Votes Seats %Votes Proportion Proportion2
Australian
Labor Party
|
4,711,363
|
72
|
37.99
|
.38
|
.14
|
Liberal
Party of Australia
|
3,777,383
|
44
|
30.46
|
.3
|
.09
|
Liberal
National Party
|
1,130,525
|
21
|
9.12
|
.09
|
.0081
|
National
Party of Australia
|
419,286
|
6
|
3.43
|
.034
|
.0012
|
Country
Liberal Party
|
38,335
|
1
|
.31
|
.0031
|
.00001
|
Australian
Greens
|
1,458,998
|
1
|
11.76
|
.12
|
.014
|
National
Party
|
43,101
|
1
|
.34
|
.0034
|
.00001
|
Totals
|
11,578,991
|
150(omits independents)
|
100% (Omits independents and parties without seats)
|
|
.25332
|
The total of all of the proportions
squared is .25332, which, when inversed, equals 3.95. However, it is very much
worth noting that The Liberal Party of Australia and The National Party of
Australia have been in coalition since 1944, and both the Liberal National
Party and the Country Liberal party have since joined them, which in and of
itself is an evidence of the veracity of Duverger’s Law. Under the law, SMDP
systems supposedly filter out smaller parties and limit a country to two
effective parties by either coalition or process of elimination. Although the
equation for determining the effective number of parties for Australia yields a
result of four, multiple parties are in coalition4, creating the
condition of a legislature essentially dominated by two parties, which stands
in agreement with Duverger’s Law.
The
lack of traction of small parties in Australia is a direct result of the
electoral rules of the state. Although there are 148 districts, which would
seem to favor the smaller parties, their candidates don’t seem to have any sort
of meaningful geographical concentration, and therefore do not garner the
sufficient amount of votes (50%+1) to land a legislative post. Aside from the
main parties (two for all intents and purposes), no party holds more than one
seat in the House of Representatives. The single transferrable vote system,
coupled with the necessity of a 50% majority creates a suffocating climate for
smaller parties given the geographical distribution of districts. This sort of
environment causes smaller parties to disappear or merge, as seen in the merger
of the four aforementioned coalition parties.
All
of Australia’s electoral institutions and implements lend credibility to the
work of Maurice Duverger. Australia typifies the SMDP structure, and as a
result, has two effective parties, as our pal Maurice predicted. Were it a PR
system, more seats would be awarded to smaller parties, such as the Australian
Greens, who received 12% of the vote in 2010 but only landed one seat. Where
Australia is concerned, Duverger’s Law holds true.
______________________________
1 “Power and Choice: An Introduction to Political Science”.
W. Phillips Shively. McGraw-Hill, New York City. 2012. P.233.
2 “Australia: House of Representatives”. Inter-Parliamentary
Union. http://www.ipu.org/parline-e/reports/2015_A.htm.
October 9,2012.
3 Lecture on October 29,2012. Dr. Kirk Hawkins. Brigham
Young University.
4“Elections in Australia”. Wikipedia Electionworld. http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Elections_in_Australia.
Accessed 11/1/12.
Wow, good job thoroughly researching this blog! Great post.
ReplyDeleteSo I guess when the parties don't reach a majority, they form coalitions. In a way, I guess that means Duverger's theory is still true: there still are two dominant parties in SMDP systems. Good research.
ReplyDeleteYOu gave a lot of background and analysis, you can tell you put research and time into it, good Job!
ReplyDelete